Episode Transcript
Bloomberg Audio Studios, podcasts, radio news.
Speaker 2I'm Stephanie Flanders, head of Government and Economics at Bloomberg, and this is trump Anomics, the podcast that looks at the economic world of Donald Trump, how he's already shaped the global economy, what on earth is going to happen next?
And this week we're talking about the price of money, why it's going up, and why that matters to all of us, and especially to governments with big debts like France, where it's part of why the government just collapsed.
Who also want to explain why this big shift in the most important price in the global economy is not entirely caused by Donald Trump, though he might be speeding the process up.
Now, when I say the price of money, I mean the interest rate.
So just like anything you buy phones, fruit, money also has a price, but instead of paying for money with other goods, we pay for it with interest.
And that price of money, that interest rate matters because it touches everything.
What you pay for a home, how much companies invest, where the prices rise too fast, even how strong a country's currency is, Who or what sets the price of money?
Well, short term, yes, central banks play their part.
We all write a lot about that piece, but long term, that price is set by a wide range of structural factors that we're going to get into in this show, and I thought we should talk about it this week.
Well, for a few reasons.
First, it's a reminder that this would have been a challenging time for governments anyway, even without Donald Trump turning the world upside down.
The second reason is we're seeing the consequences of a higher cost of borrowing play out in real time this month, as bond yields the government interest rates go up in many countries.
France I've already mentioned, now pays more than Italy to borrow from the market.
It's also arguably rising bond year that is the one factor more than any other, putting serious financial pressure on the labor government in the UK.
But yes, I'll admit the final reason is because we at Bloomberg Economics have written a book that explains it all, The Price of Money, A Guide to the past, present and Future of the natural Rate of Interest.
It's published a few weeks ago by Oxford University Press, and it is available I'm told at all fine bookstores, and my two lead co authors who face it did most of the work pulling that book together.
Are here with me now.
Jamie Rush, the director of Global Economics at Bloomberg, who's here in London and joining again from the Washington studio, Tom Orlick, who's chief economist for Bloomberg Economics.
Jamie, Tom, thanks very much for being here to hawk card book.
We don't usually get to say that.
Speaker 1Thank you for having me.
Speaker 3Great to be here, Stephanie.
Speaker 2Tom, let me start with you.
You know, I've said a little bit about it, but why is it important now to think about the long term cost of money?
Because for many people that will seem pretty abstract.
Speaker 3So I think there's a few factors at work, Stephanie.
So the first is, this is a moment for the global markets.
This is a moment where across Europe, across Japan, in the United States, long term interest rates are high, and in many of those places they're rising, with far reaching consequences for governments, for businesses, for households, for investors.
I think the second reason is, well, there are some really long term factors that drive the rate of interest, things like demographics, for example, but there's also some important factors that are playing out right now.
So think about Donald Trump and the end of the Pax Americana, the US security guarantee.
That's forcing everyone from European NATO allies to Japan and Korea and Taiwan to significantly increase their defense spending.
And when they do that, when governments borrow to increase defense spending, that puts upward pressure on interest rates.
So it's a market moment, but it's also a kind of paradigm shift moment for the global economy, and I think that's one reason that makes this new book timely.
Speaker 2You can see how many book references the book we can get in now, Jamie, looking at quite a lot of examples now where this is playing out.
Tell us, just as example of France, how some of these forces are pushing up the cost of borrow and indeed helping to cause you know, yet another government to collapse this week.
Speaker 1Well, there are certainly a handful of economies globally which are sort of in the cross hairs of markets, and they've seen interest rates go up by the most.
So you mentioned France.
Largely that's because the parliament is very fractured and it's going to be very very difficult for them to pass any legislation which gets the budget under control.
We saw in Japan the interest rates at the long end of the curve moved up.
Why because the central bankers ditched your curve control.
And if you ditch your co control, you no longer have control of your curve.
And in the UK, where there's a significant amount of gloom and pessimism about the government's ability to rain in debt, all of these things are serving to push up interest rates.
But actually these idiosyncratic things are not the main source of the movement up in interest rates.
If you look at which part is local and which part is global, you see that there's a huge global element to rising borrowing costs around the world, and it's that part that we were trying to think about when we did our analysis.
Speaker 2I guess this is partly just the supply of money and the demand for money.
We think of the demand for money being things that you need to invest in or governments might be wanting to borrow.
And the supply of money is the savings and other sources of cash that are sitting around the economy.
Over the previous decade, people whused to talk about the savings glut.
There was a lot of money sloshing around and potentially fewer places for it to go.
So governments were able to borrow very cheaply because there was a lot of money.
But now that shift is churning.
Talk us through that sort of demand and supply forces, because obviously it relates to what you just said.
Speaker 3Yes, exactly it.
Speaker 1So it's the balance of saving an investment in the global economy that matters for global interest rates, and they're all determined with that global factory in mind.
And for many years, the global cost of borrowing was falling, and the reason for that was because investment was getting cheaper.
We had all this these cheap goods coming from China.
Much cheaper to upgrade your technology, for example, you don't have to spend so much on investment.
That was one of the by products of globalization.
On the saving side, you have the baby boomers socking away their paychecks into their savings accounts, preparing for retirement.
That also helped push down the cost money and defense spending.
For example, well after the Cold War, we thought the world seemed relatively safe, and so governments saved.
They didn't They reduce their military budgets and they save the money all of these things are now starting to spin into reverse.
So globalization, which helped keep investment goods cheap and actually inflation down, well that's not going to be proceeding at the same pace as it was.
Defense spending where we don't live in a safe world.
It's becoming much more dangerous.
We need to ramp up defense spending like Tom was describing.
And the demographics side of things, well, yes, the baby boomers are now retiring, and so they're going to be drawing down their savings rather than pushing money into them, and so all of these factors are shifting that fundamental balance between saving and investment in the global economy, and that is going to help push interest rates up.
Speaker 2Tom, we've said it's not all down to Donald Trump, and you could just hear from that list it's clearly not all down to Donald Trump, much though he might like to make the political and economic weather while he's in office.
But you can also hear in that list number of things which are at least are being given the kind of extra impetus by his policies.
And I guess we also have the possibility for sort of supply chain issues or reversing globalization, which you would think, given that it was contributing to falling prices in previous decades, if that's contributing to rising prices and potentially come of more variability in prices, more kind of shocks for central banks to manage, well, that too might be a way in which he's contributing to higher rates overall.
Is that right?
Yeah?
Speaker 3I think there's a multiple dimensions on which the Trump administration is driving interest rates higher, Stephanie.
Perhaps the first of them, as you mentioned, is the shock to the global system.
It was the integration of a billion low cost Chinese workers into the global trade system, which helped keep a lid on inflation in the US through the Great Moderation.
I think many people expected the addition of a billion Indian local cost workers to extend that trend in the decades ahead.
Donald Trump, with his tariffs is signaling well, that's just not going to happen.
Borrowing in the United States is really high.
Trump's Big Beautiful Bill adds very significantly to the fiscal deficit over the next decade.
Some three trillion added to US debt according to the Congressional Budget Office, And when the US Treasury is issuing more debt well, they're going to have to pay more to borrow, and that means interest rates go up as well.
Lastly, of course, there are the attacks on FED independence.
Now, the impact on interest rates there is a little bit complicated.
If Trump gets his way and gets a more pliant FED chair and a more pliant FED board, well he could get short term interest rates down, and the impact of that ripples through the yield curve, so it also has an impact on long term rates as well.
The bigger impact, though, would likely be a blow to the Fed's credibility as an inflation fighter, and that would mean that investors would demand a premium to lend to the US government, to the US Treasury, and that too is a force pushing up longer term borrowing costs.
Speaker 2We've mentioned the UK, We've mentioned France, and we know from previous episodes that the borrowing in the US has been continued to be very high.
And then the government deficit is very high for a country that is actually not in the middle of a recession.
It's been running this kind of four or five six percent of GDP budget deficits.
And we've just had that big beautiful bill, as he called it, pasted in Congress, which added enormously to future debt.
And yet I was amazed to see the other day that of one of the few developed countries that has seen its sort of ten year borrowing rate go down slightly since the beginning of the year is actually the US.
So, Tom, how is the US getting away with that?
I mean, yields are obviously higher, and they're higher than when Donald Trump took office or when he was elected, but not as much high.
We haven't seen the kind of impact that you might have expected.
Speaker 3Yeah, So a few thoughts on that.
The first one is if we sort of extend the span of history a little bit longer, the big picture is very much, very low ten year borrowing costs before the COVID shock, very low ten yure borrowing costs at the end of the twenty tens, and significantly higher borrowing costs today.
So yes, absolutely, the US has been one of the countries that has had that ten year rate nudge down since the start of the year.
But if we pull the historical frame back a bit, the US is still very much in the group of countries which had very low borrowing costs a few years ago, a much higher borrowing costs today.
Now, why haven't US borrowing costs gone up so far this year?
Maybe it's useful to think about kind of three different groups of countries.
You've got your fragile emerging markets that are very dependent on portfolio capital flows, and there's big questions about the quality of their institutions, places like Turkey or Argentina.
If they make a policy error, all the money flows out straight away, interest rates spike higher, currencies plunge lower, and the impact are very real and very rapid.
Then you've got advanced economies where the quality of institutions is stronger and investors have a higher degree of confidence.
But they're still small relative to the size of the global economy, and so when they make policy missteps they face some pretty rapid and severe consequences as well.
Think about the UK under the Trust administration.
The US perhaps is in a category of its own right, the world's biggest economy, the world's deepest financial markets, the world's most powerful military, a history of good governance, even if there are growing concerns about erosion of institutions right now, and for a country like the United States, the issue of the world's reserve currency.
I think what you have is just much more capacity to play fast and loose with the rules before facing the real consequences.
Perhaps this is an opportunity for me to surface my favorite quote from The Great Gatsby, how did you go bankrupt?
First slowly, then all at once?
Speaker 2Well, we've been pointing to some ways in which that might happen on this show, Jamie, I want to take off a couple of things, because we've gone through a lot of factors.
But there'll be some people listening who will think of other ways in which the world's changing and will be interested to know how this affects the cost of money.
One thing we do talk about in the book is inequality, and one thing that seems destined to continue, although individual countries have had different experiences, but the sort of emergence of the sort of super wealthy and apparently much more unequal division of wealth.
You wealth obviously plays a big part in savings and investment.
How is that going to affect to the cost of money.
Speaker 1The mechanism at play here is that people at the top end of the income distribution saved more, their earnings have gone up faster than their capacity to buy cpots, and then so they're putting that in their bank accounts, and so over the past few decades or so, as income inequality has moved upwards, perhaps contributed more to savings and it helped to contain borrowing costs or push them down.
Looking ahead, our view is that income inequality is not likely to rise by as much as it has over the previous few decades, largely because it has risen so much already and it would require significant policy change.
But clearly with the direction of travel in US, policy is likely to climb a little further, and again that will continue to exert some downward pressure on interest rates going ahead.
Speaker 2And if we move more slowly or faster towards a net zero goal when it comes to the carbon transition, how does that affect things, Because that's obviously one of those areas where we've had in the book, we've had to have a pretty big range of uncertainty.
Speaker 1Yeah, So I think that the impacts of climate change on rates, or at least the research into it, still in its infancy, So you have so many unknown It's not just about economics, but the impact of global heating on the economy, and so I think you need to think about it through two lenses.
One is what are the physical damages that climate change does the global economy, Because the more damage it does, the slower growth will be, the lower the inherent rate of return in the economy will be, and that will push down on interest rates.
But going in the opposite direction, if the world gets serious about tackling climate change, it's going to take huge investments in energy infrastructure to green the economy.
And if you look at what new economy finance being there for saying at Bloomberg, we're talking about trillion dollar investments here, and so that extra spending that's required, that extra investment would push interest rates up, and we think that if there is a significant push, then the net effect is more likely to be upwards on borrowing costs than downwards.
Speaker 2That rais is interesting point, and that actually it was one of the things I think a bit about in the final chapter of the book, when you sort of think about what are the implications of this change for governments, for businesses and others.
I mean, we've tended to describe the cost of money going up as like a negative thing, a challenge, a headwind, and it certainly is for governments.
If you have a lot of debt.
It could also happen, as we describe, for reasons that we could be quite happy about.
It could be a world of higher interest rates, could be a world in which we all might prefer to live in.
I mean, we obviously savers it's better for them if they have higher interest rates.
We've already seen in a kind of small way, companies find it all be easier to cover their pension obligations because that higher interest rate means that future money that their promise to pensioners is worth a bit less in today's money than it was in the period where rates were extremely low and we had all those big holes in pension funds.
But what else could be better about a higher rate world?
Speaker 1Think about AI as an example here specifically, So what will AI due to the natural rate?
Well, to realize that the promise of this technology, you have to pile a huge amount of money into it, and that will tend to push interest rates up.
But at the same time, the benefits could be huge and growth could be faster.
Income growth could be faster, people could be better off.
So it's in spite of the higher interest rate environment, people will be on the whole quite significantly better off.
So I think that's kind of a good example of how interest rates can move for good reasons, they can move for bad reasons, and it's not always clear which is which.
Speaker 2I guess.
If there's lots of demand for money, that could be, as you say, people desperately wanting to use it to build green energy and to have a much faster, more dramatic approach to prevent climate change.
It could be that they want to use it for all these exciting investments, and this is what we seem to be seeing.
If it's for governments to desperately cover their rising bills from aging populations and creaking health services, then that's less of a positive.
Speaker 1Yeah, And I think that's the big risk, isn't it.
So if you look at aging populations, you should expect probably that the tax to GDP ratio and move in line with the dependency ratio.
Such the older population more outlays higher taxes.
But if you look at how divided parliaments are across advanced economies, the actual ability of governance to raise taxes in line with those liabilities is extremely low.
So if they can't.
If they can't do that, then you're just going to borrow more interest rates will therefore rise and you end up in this bad equilibrium.
Speaker 2And that's what sounds a little bit similar to what the finances of the Chancellor in the UK is grappling with as we head towards this budget, which as always is being billed as sort of a make or break budget.
But the fundamental thing she's trying to avoid really is people noticing that the tax rate, tax share of GDP's gone up, but it seems almost inevitable that it will.
Tom Jamie's already said individual countries can't change the global supply and demand for money, and maybe even the US is going to to some extent be a taker of these forces, not a maker, although Donald Trump's doing his best to change that.
What do you think about, just as a final thought about how to prepare, you know, or do better or worse in this world where money becomes more expensive, I guess I'm thinking a little bit as household but also as a government.
Speaker 3So, first of all, Stephanie, for any of the rich people out there who heard Jamie's comments about inadequate demand as a kind of blight on the broader economy and wants to do their bits to address the problem, they could buy copy of our book.
It won't fundamentally solve the problem, but every little bit helps.
So coming back to your question, one of the things which I find really fun about working on this book with the Bloomberg Economics team is that it just touches such a rich variety of subjects.
Right, So, what drives the natural rate of interest?
Well, it's about climate change, it's about artificial intelligence, it's about demographics, it's about deglobalization.
And one of the interesting things about writing the book was the we had to get to grips with all of these subjects, but we had to get to grips with them in a very specific way, right, with a very specific angle.
It's not what does climate change mean for everybody's life in the future of the planet, It's what does climate change mean for the balance between saving an investment?
Right.
So, in a sense, if some of the predictions which we have in the book play out, people are going to have other stuff to worry about.
Right.
They're going to be living in a much hotter planet, or they're going to be living in a world where robots are thinking for themselves, or they're going to be thinking of living in a world where there's much more, much more conflict, and much more defense spending.
But in terms of the focus of the book on interest rates, from the early nineteen eighties to the mid twenty tens, we were living in a world a US, a Europe where interest rates were on a structural declining trend.
Right, it was getting cheaper and cheaper to borrow, and that had far reaching consequences for everybody.
If you're an investor in equity markets or property, you made a lot of money because were coming down and money was piling into those markets.
If you were a minister of finance, you could borrow more cheaply and not really face a bill for piling on debt.
Now, with rates rising, all of those trends swinging into reverse, right, and so we don't have low interest rates as a upward driver of equity and property markets.
We have rising interest rates as a drag on equity and property markets.
We don't have low interest rates giving ministers of finance a free lunch.
We've got higher interest rates, which means the bill is about to arrive.
Speaker 2But typically upbeat economists answer, well, I guess money doesn't make the world go around, but maybe it does make economics more interesting for all of us.
And I guess the moral of what you just said, Thomas.
If the price is money is going up, it's going to be even more important to spend it and borrow it wisely.
Tom Warlick, Jamie Rush, thank you so much.
Speaker 3Thank you.
Thanks definitely great to be here.
Speaker 2Thanks for listening to Trumponomics from Bloomberg.
It was hosted by me Stephanie Flanders.
I was joined by Bloomberg's Tom Orlick and Jamie Rush.
Trumponomics was produced by Samasadi and Moses Dam with help from a Keen and special thanks this week to Rachel Lewis Kriskey.
Sound design is by Blake Maples and Kelly Gary and Sage Bowman is Bloomberg's head of podcast And please help others find this show and enjoy it by rating and reviewing it highly wherever you listen